💸Principles of Economics Unit 9 – Monopoly

Monopolies, a market structure with a single seller and no close substitutes, wield significant market power. They form through legal barriers, resource control, or economies of scale, allowing them to set prices above marginal cost and earn long-term profits. Unlike perfect competition, monopolies face downward-sloping demand curves and create inefficiencies. Governments regulate monopolies through antitrust laws and price controls to promote competition and protect consumers. Real-world examples include utilities, sports leagues, and tech giants.

What's a Monopoly?

  • A market structure characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes
  • Monopolies have significant market power and can influence the price of their product
  • Barriers to entry prevent new firms from entering the market and competing with the monopoly
  • Monopolies face the market demand curve, which is downward sloping, unlike perfectly competitive firms
  • The absence of competition allows monopolies to charge higher prices and earn economic profits in the long run
  • Monopolies may engage in price discrimination, charging different prices to different consumers based on their willingness to pay
  • Natural monopolies arise when a single firm can supply the entire market at a lower cost than multiple firms (utilities, railroads)

How Monopolies Form

  • Legal barriers, such as patents, copyrights, and government licenses, grant exclusive rights to a single firm
    • Patents protect inventions and give the patent holder the sole right to produce and sell the product for a specified period (pharmaceuticals)
    • Copyrights protect original works of authorship, such as books, music, and software (Microsoft Windows)
  • Control over essential resources or inputs can create a monopoly if a single firm has exclusive access to a critical resource (De Beers and diamonds)
  • High start-up costs and economies of scale can deter potential competitors from entering the market
  • Government regulations or policies may create or support monopolies by limiting competition (public utilities)
  • Network effects can lead to a monopoly when the value of a product increases with the number of users (Facebook, Instagram)
  • Mergers and acquisitions can result in a monopoly if a firm buys out its competitors or potential rivals
  • Technological superiority or innovation can give a firm a significant advantage over competitors, leading to a monopoly (Google's search engine)

Market Power and Pricing

  • Monopolies have significant market power, which is the ability to influence the price of their product
  • Unlike perfectly competitive firms, monopolies are price makers, not price takers
  • Monopolies face a downward-sloping demand curve, meaning they must lower the price to sell more units
  • The marginal revenue curve for a monopoly lies below the demand curve because the firm must lower the price on all units to sell an additional unit
  • Monopolies set prices above marginal cost, leading to higher prices compared to perfectly competitive markets
  • The markup, or the difference between price and marginal cost, depends on the elasticity of demand
    • The more inelastic the demand, the higher the markup and the greater the monopoly's market power
  • Monopolies may engage in price discrimination, charging different prices to different consumers based on their willingness to pay (student discounts, senior discounts)

Profit Maximization in Monopolies

  • Like all firms, monopolies aim to maximize their profits
  • To maximize profits, a monopoly produces at the quantity where marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MR = MC)
  • The profit-maximizing price is determined by the demand curve at the profit-maximizing quantity
  • Monopolies earn economic profits in the long run because barriers to entry prevent new firms from entering the market
  • The absence of competition allows monopolies to maintain prices above marginal cost and earn positive economic profits
  • Monopoly profits can be represented as the area between the price and the average total cost curve at the profit-maximizing quantity
  • The profit-maximizing quantity is lower than the socially optimal quantity, which occurs where the demand curve intersects the marginal cost curve
  • Monopolies have no supply curve because their output decision depends on both the demand and marginal revenue curves

Efficiency and Deadweight Loss

  • Monopolies are allocatively inefficient because they produce less than the socially optimal quantity and charge a price above marginal cost
  • The socially optimal quantity occurs where the demand curve intersects the marginal cost curve
  • Monopolies create a deadweight loss, which is the loss of consumer and producer surplus due to the underproduction and overpricing of the monopoly
  • Deadweight loss is represented by the triangular area between the demand curve, the marginal cost curve, and the monopoly quantity
  • Monopolies also tend to be productively inefficient because they lack the competitive pressure to minimize costs and operate at the minimum of the average total cost curve
  • The absence of competition may lead to X-inefficiency, where monopolies have higher costs due to a lack of incentive to control costs
  • Monopolies may have less incentive to innovate and improve their products because they face no competitive threat
  • The misallocation of resources and the loss of consumer and producer surplus make monopolies less efficient than perfectly competitive markets

Regulation and Antitrust Laws

  • Governments may intervene in monopoly markets to promote competition, protect consumers, and reduce inefficiencies
  • Antitrust laws, such as the Sherman Act and the Clayton Act in the United States, prohibit anticompetitive practices and mergers that substantially lessen competition
  • Regulatory agencies, such as the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the Department of Justice (DOJ), enforce antitrust laws
  • Price regulation can be used to limit the prices charged by natural monopolies or firms with significant market power (electricity rates, telephone rates)
  • Rate-of-return regulation sets prices to allow the monopoly to earn a fair rate of return on its invested capital
  • Price cap regulation sets a maximum price the monopoly can charge, which is adjusted periodically for inflation and productivity improvements
  • Governments may also promote competition by breaking up monopolies into smaller firms (AT&T breakup in 1984) or by requiring monopolies to grant access to essential facilities (telecom networks)
  • Antitrust enforcement can prevent mergers that would create or strengthen a monopoly (Microsoft antitrust case)

Real-World Monopoly Examples

  • Public utilities, such as water and electricity providers, are often natural monopolies due to the high fixed costs of infrastructure (power grids, water pipelines)
  • Professional sports leagues, such as the NFL and NBA, have monopoly power over their respective sports in the United States
  • De Beers had a near-monopoly on the global diamond market for much of the 20th century by controlling the majority of the world's diamond supply
  • Microsoft had a monopoly in the personal computer operating system market with its Windows software, leading to antitrust lawsuits in the 1990s and 2000s
  • Google has a dominant market share in online search and search advertising, raising concerns about its market power and potential anticompetitive practices
  • Patents grant pharmaceutical companies monopoly rights over their drugs for a specified period, allowing them to charge higher prices (Lipitor, Viagra)
  • Local cable television providers often have monopolies in their service areas due to the high costs of building and maintaining the necessary infrastructure

Monopoly vs. Perfect Competition

  • Monopolies and perfectly competitive markets are at opposite ends of the market structure spectrum
  • In perfect competition, there are many small firms selling identical products, while in a monopoly, there is a single seller of a unique product
  • Perfectly competitive firms are price takers, while monopolies are price makers
  • Perfectly competitive firms face a horizontal demand curve, while monopolies face a downward-sloping demand curve
  • In the long run, perfectly competitive firms earn zero economic profits, while monopolies can earn positive economic profits
  • Perfectly competitive markets are allocatively and productively efficient, while monopolies are inefficient and create deadweight loss
  • In perfect competition, firms produce at the point where price equals marginal cost (P = MC), while monopolies produce where marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MR = MC)
  • Perfectly competitive firms have no market power, while monopolies have significant market power and can influence the price of their product
  • The entry and exit of firms in perfectly competitive markets ensure that prices remain at the level of marginal cost, while barriers to entry in monopoly markets allow for sustained economic profits


© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.

© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.