💰Intro to Mathematical Economics Unit 11 – General Equilibrium in Economics
General equilibrium theory examines how multiple markets interact to determine prices and allocations in an economy. It analyzes supply, demand, and prices across interconnected markets, contrasting with partial equilibrium's focus on a single market in isolation.
Key concepts include Walrasian equilibrium, Pareto efficiency, and competitive equilibrium. The theory uses mathematical tools like set theory, vector spaces, and optimization techniques to model complex economic interactions and prove the existence of equilibrium states.
General equilibrium analyzes the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with multiple interacting markets
Partial equilibrium focuses on a single market in isolation, assuming that other markets remain unchanged
Walrasian equilibrium named after Léon Walras, is a state where all markets simultaneously clear and demand equals supply for all commodities
Pareto efficiency occurs when no individual can be made better off without making at least one other individual worse off
Edgeworth box is a graphical tool used to analyze the trading of two goods between two people, representing the preferences and endowments of both parties
Competitive equilibrium is a situation in which the market price is such that the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded, and no market participant has an incentive to alter their behavior
Excess demand is the situation where the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied at a given price level
Excess supply occurs when the quantity supplied exceeds the quantity demanded at a given price level
Mathematical Foundations
Set theory is used to define the basic elements of the economy, such as the set of consumers, producers, and commodities
Example: Let I={1,2,...,m} be the set of consumers and J={1,2,...,n} be the set of producers
Vector spaces are employed to represent the consumption bundles and production plans
Example: A consumption bundle for a consumer i is represented as xi=(xi1,xi2,...,xil)∈R+l
Convex analysis is crucial for studying the properties of preference relations and production sets
A set X⊆Rn is convex if for any x,y∈X and λ∈[0,1], λx+(1−λ)y∈X
Optimization techniques are used to characterize the behavior of consumers and producers
Consumers maximize utility subject to budget constraints, while producers maximize profits subject to technological constraints
Fixed point theorems, such as Brouwer's and Kakutani's, are employed to prove the existence of equilibrium
Brouwer's fixed point theorem states that any continuous function from a compact and convex set to itself has a fixed point
General Equilibrium Model Setup
The economy consists of a finite number of consumers I={1,2,...,m} and producers J={1,2,...,n}
There are a finite number of commodities L={1,2,...,l} in the economy
Each consumer i has a preference relation ≿i over the consumption set Xi⊆R+l and an initial endowment ωi∈R+l
The preference relation is typically assumed to be complete, transitive, and locally non-satiated
Each producer j has a production set Yj⊆Rl representing the feasible production plans
The production set is usually assumed to be closed, convex, and satisfying the no free lunch condition (i.e., Yj∩R+l={0})
The total endowment of the economy is given by ω=∑i=1mωi
A price vector is an element of the price space P=R+l, where pk represents the price of commodity k
Walrasian Equilibrium
A Walrasian equilibrium is a price vector p∗∈P and an allocation (x∗,y∗) such that:
For each consumer i, xi∗ maximizes ≿i subject to the budget constraint p∗⋅xi≤p∗⋅ωi+∑j=1nθijp∗⋅yj∗
For each producer j, yj∗ maximizes profits p∗⋅yj over the production set Yj
Markets clear: ∑i=1mxi∗=ω+∑j=1nyj∗
In equilibrium, consumers maximize their utility given prices and budget constraints, producers maximize profits given prices and production sets, and markets clear
The budget constraint for each consumer includes the value of their initial endowment and their share of profits from producers, where θij represents consumer i's ownership share in producer j
The market clearing condition ensures that the total consumption equals the total endowment plus the total production
Existence and Uniqueness of Equilibrium
The existence of a Walrasian equilibrium is a fundamental question in general equilibrium theory
Arrow-Debreu existence theorem provides sufficient conditions for the existence of a Walrasian equilibrium
The theorem requires assumptions such as convex preferences, convex production sets, and a bounded economy
Kakutani's fixed point theorem is a key tool in proving the existence of equilibrium
It states that a upper hemicontinuous, nonempty-, convex-, and compact-valued correspondence from a convex and compact set to itself has a fixed point
The uniqueness of equilibrium is not guaranteed in general and depends on the specific properties of the economy
Gross substitutability of commodities is a sufficient condition for uniqueness, but it is a strong assumption
Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem highlights the difficulty of obtaining uniqueness, as it shows that any continuous and homogeneous excess demand function can be rationalized as the excess demand of an economy with well-behaved consumers and producers
Efficiency and Welfare Analysis
Pareto efficiency is a central concept in welfare analysis of general equilibrium
An allocation is Pareto efficient if there is no other feasible allocation that makes at least one individual better off without making anyone else worse off
First Welfare Theorem states that, under certain assumptions (no externalities, complete markets, perfect competition), any Walrasian equilibrium is Pareto efficient
This theorem provides a strong justification for the efficiency of competitive markets
Second Welfare Theorem asserts that, under similar assumptions, any Pareto efficient allocation can be supported as a Walrasian equilibrium with appropriate redistribution of initial endowments
This theorem suggests that efficiency and equity can be separated, and any desired Pareto efficient allocation can be achieved through lump-sum transfers followed by competitive exchange
Social welfare functions, such as the utilitarian or the Rawlsian, can be used to evaluate and compare different allocations based on the society's value judgments
The utilitarian social welfare function seeks to maximize the sum of individual utilities, while the Rawlsian focuses on maximizing the utility of the worst-off individual
Compensating and equivalent variations are monetary measures of welfare changes that can be used to quantify the impact of policy interventions or economic shocks on individuals
Applications and Real-World Examples
International trade theory uses general equilibrium models to analyze the patterns of trade and the welfare effects of trade policies
The Heckscher-Ohlin model explains trade patterns based on differences in factor endowments across countries (labor and capital)
Public finance employs general equilibrium frameworks to study the efficiency and distributional impacts of tax policies
The Diamond-Mirrlees production efficiency theorem shows that, under certain conditions, optimal tax systems should not distort production decisions
Environmental economics utilizes general equilibrium models to examine the interaction between the economy and the environment
Integrated assessment models (IAMs) combine economic and climate modules to analyze the costs and benefits of climate policies (carbon taxes or emission permits)
Macroeconomic models, such as the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models, are based on the general equilibrium framework and are used for policy analysis and forecasting
The Real Business Cycle (RBC) model explains economic fluctuations as the result of real shocks (technology shocks) propagating through a competitive economy
Urban economics employs spatial general equilibrium models to study the location choices of households and firms and the formation of cities
The Alonso-Muth-Mills model analyzes the trade-off between housing prices and commuting costs in determining the urban spatial structure
Common Pitfalls and Misconceptions
Assuming that partial equilibrium analysis always provides accurate insights, ignoring the potential spillover effects across markets
For example, analyzing the impact of a subsidy on a single market without considering the general equilibrium effects on related markets
Interpreting the First Welfare Theorem as a blanket justification for laissez-faire policies, neglecting the importance of the underlying assumptions (no externalities, complete markets, perfect competition)
Market failures, such as externalities or public goods, can lead to inefficient outcomes even in competitive equilibrium
Overemphasizing the normative implications of the Second Welfare Theorem without considering the practical difficulties of implementing lump-sum transfers
Lump-sum transfers are rarely feasible in practice due to information constraints and political economy considerations
Treating the existence of a Walrasian equilibrium as a guarantee of its stability or convergence under tatonnement processes
The stability of equilibrium depends on the specific adjustment processes and the properties of excess demand functions
Neglecting the potential multiplicity of equilibria and the resulting coordination problems
In the presence of increasing returns or externalities, there may be multiple equilibria, and the economy may get stuck in a suboptimal equilibrium
Assuming that the competitive equilibrium always results in a socially desirable outcome, ignoring distributional concerns and the limitations of the Pareto criterion
The Pareto criterion does not take into account the initial distribution of resources or the fairness of the allocation
Overreliance on representative agent models, which may obscure important heterogeneity and distributional issues
Representative agent models assume that all individuals have identical preferences and endowments, which may not capture the diversity of real-world economies
Ignoring the bounded rationality and behavioral biases of economic agents, which may lead to deviations from the predictions of standard general equilibrium models
Behavioral economics has shown that individuals may exhibit loss aversion, hyperbolic discounting, or other biases that are not captured by the standard rational choice framework